Developing countries' alarming capital drain

A miner at work in South Africa. Falling demand for natural resources in China has led to sharp declines in their prices, which have hit many developing and emerging economies in Latin America and Africa hard. Their worry is not just falling commodit
A miner at work in South Africa. Falling demand for natural resources in China has led to sharp declines in their prices, which have hit many developing and emerging economies in Latin America and Africa hard. Their worry is not just falling commodity prices, but also massive capital outflows. PHOTO: REUTERS

NEW YORK • Developing countries are bracing themselves for a major slowdown. According to the UN report World Economic Situation and Prospects 2016, their growth will average only 3.8 per cent this year - the lowest rate since the global financial crisis in 2009 and matched in this century only by the recessionary year of 2001. And what is important to bear in mind is that the slowdown in China and the deep recessions in the Russian Federation and Brazil explain only part of the broad falloff in growth.

True, falling demand for natural resources in China (which accounts for nearly half of global demand for base metals) has had a lot to do with the sharp declines in these prices, which have hit many developing and emerging economies in Latin America and Africa hard. Indeed, the UN report lists 29 economies that are likely to be badly affected by China's slowdown. And the collapse of oil prices by more than 60 per cent since July 2014 has undermined oil exporters' growth prospects.

The real worry, however, is not just falling commodity prices, but also massive capital outflows. During 2009-2014, developing countries collectively received a net capital inflow of US$2.2 trillion (S$3.04 trillion), partly owing to quantitative easing in advanced economies, which pushed interest rates there to nearly zero.

The search for higher yields drove investors and speculators to developing countries, where the inflows increased leverage, propped up equity prices, and in some cases supported a commodity price boom. Market capitalisation in the Mumbai, Johannesburg, Sao Paulo and Shanghai stock exchanges, for example, nearly tripled in the years following the financial crisis. Equity markets in other developing countries witnessed similar dramatic increases during this period.

But the capital flows are now reversing, turning negative for the first time since 2006, with net outflows from developing countries last year exceeding US$600 billion - more than one-quarter of the inflows they received during the previous six years. The largest outflows have been through banking channels, with international banks reducing their gross credit exposures to developing countries by more than US$800 billion last year. Capital outflows of this magnitude are likely to have myriad effects: drying up liquidity, increasing the costs of borrowing and debt service, weakening currencies, depleting reserves, and leading to decreases in equity and other asset prices. There will be large knock-on effects on the real economy, including severe damage to developing countries' growth prospects.

A miner at work in South Africa. Falling demand for natural resources in China has led to sharp declines in their prices, which have hit many developing and emerging economies in Latin America and Africa hard. Their worry is not just falling commodity prices, but also massive capital outflows. PHOTO: REUTERS

This is not the first time that developing countries are facing the challenges of managing pro-cyclical hot capital, but the magnitudes this time are overwhelming. During the Asian financial crisis, net outflows from the East Asian economies were only US$12 billion in 1997.

Of course, the East Asian economies today are better able to withstand massive outflows, given their accumulation of international reserves since the financial crisis in 1997. Indeed, the global stock of reserves has more than tripled since the crisis. China, for example, used nearly US$500 billion of its reserves last year to fight capital outflows and prevent the renminbi's sharp depreciation, but it still has more than US$3 trillion in reserves.

The stockpile of reserves may partly explain why huge outflows have not triggered a full-blown financial crisis in developing countries. But not all countries are so fortunate to have a large arsenal.

Once again, advocates of free mobility for destabilising short-term capital flows are being proven wrong. Many emerging markets recognised the dangers and tried to reduce capital inflows. South Korea, for example, has been using a series of macroprudential measures since 2010, aimed at moderating pro-cyclical cross-border banking-sector liabilities. The measures taken were only partially successful. What should they do now?

Corporate sectors in developing countries, having increased their leverage with capital inflows during the post-2008 period, are particularly vulnerable. Capital outflows will adversely affect their equity prices, push up their debt-to-equity ratios and increase the likelihood of defaults. The problem is especially severe in commodity-exporting developing economies, where firms borrowed extensively, expecting high commodity prices to persist.

Many developing-country governments failed to learn the lesson of earlier crises, which should have prompted regulations and taxes restricting and discouraging foreign-currency exposures. Now governments need to take quick action to avoid becoming liable for these exposures. Expedited debtor-friendly bankruptcy procedures could ensure quick restructuring and provide a framework for renegotiating debts.

Developing-country governments should encourage the conversion of such debts to GDP-linked or other types of indexed bonds. Those with high levels of foreign debt but with reserves should consider buying back their sovereign debt in the international capital market, taking advantage of falling bond prices.

While reserves may provide some cushion for minimising the adverse effects of capital outflows, in most cases they will not be sufficient. Developing countries should resist the temptation of raising interest rates to stem capital outflows. Historically, interest-rate hikes have had little effect. In fact, because they hurt economic growth, further reducing countries' ability to service external debts, higher interest rates can be counterproductive. Macro-prudential measures can discourage or delay capital outflows, but such measures, too, may be insufficient.

In some cases, it may be necessary to introduce selective, targeted and time-bound capital controls to stem outflows, especially outflows through banking channels. This would entail, for example, restricting capital transfers between parent banks in developed countries and their subsidiaries or branches in developing countries. Following the successful Malaysian example in 1997, developing countries could also temporarily suspend all capital withdrawals to stabilise capital flows and exchange rates. This is perhaps the only recourse for many developing countries to avoid a catastrophic financial crisis. It is important that they act soon.

PROJECT SYNDICATE

•Joseph E. Stiglitz, a Nobel laureate in Economics, is University Professor at Columbia University and Chief Economist of the Roosevelt Institute. Hamid Rashid is Chief of Global Economic Monitoring at the United Nations Department of Economic and Social Affairs. The views expressed here do not represent the views of the United Nations or its member states.

Join ST's Telegram channel and get the latest breaking news delivered to you.

A version of this article appeared in the print edition of The Straits Times on March 05, 2016, with the headline Developing countries' alarming capital drain. Subscribe